Qué hacer con los banqueros "codiciosos
A raíz de la crisis financiera más reciente, los organismos reguladores financieros de todo el mundo han buscado formas de frenar la asunción excesiva de riesgos por parte de los banqueros. La mayoría de las veces, esto se hace limitando las primas y desarrollando políticas de recuperación (Gray, 2016). Tales decisiones se basan en la opinión generalizada de que los incentivos financieros son un factor para la asunción de riesgos. Que la posibilidad de obtener grandes beneficios personales es tan atractiva que muchos individuos están dispuestos a asumir riesgos excesivos para conseguirlos. Esta es la visión clásica "homo-economicus" del comportamiento humano, en la que se considera a las personas actores racionales, motivados para maximizar la utilidad personal por razones de interés propio (Aktipis y Kurzban, 2004; Thaler, 2000). En otras palabras, ser codicioso.
Pero .... ¿y si los banqueros no asumieran riesgos para ganar sus primas por motivos de codicia, sino por motivos de necesidad?
References
Abdel-khalik, A. R. (2014). Prospect Theory predictions in the field: Risk seekers in settings of weak accounting controls. Journal of Accounting Literature, 33(1–2), 58–84. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.acclit.2014.10.001
Aktipis, C. A., & Kurzban, R. O. (2004). Is homo economicus extinct? Vernon Smith, Daniel Kahneman and the Evolutionary Perspective. In Advances in Austrian Economics (Vol. 7, pp. 135–153). Bingley: Emerald (MCB UP ). Retrieved from https://www.emeraldinsight.com/10.1016/S1529-2134(04)07007-3
Caraco, T., Martindale, S., & Whittam, T. S. (1980). An empirical demonstration of risk-sensitive foraging preferences. Animal Behavior, 28(3), 820–830. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0003-3472(80)80142-4
Gonzales, J., Mishra, S., & Camp, R. D. (2016). For the Win: Risk-Sensitive Decision-Making in Teams: Risk-Sensitivity in Teams. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making. https://doi.org/10.1002/bdm.1965
Gray, A. (2016). US finance professionals face fresh pay crackdown. Retrieved May 19, 2016, from https://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/49a9b30a-07d3-11e6-a623-b84d06a39ec2.html
Locke, E. A., & Latham, G. P. (2002). Building a practically useful theory of goal setting and task motivation: A 35-year odyssey. American Psychologist, 57(9), 705–717. https://doi.org/10.1037/0003-066X.57.9.705
McDermott, R., Fowler, J. H., & Smirnov, O. (2008). On the Evolutionary Origin of Prospect Theory Preferences. The Journal of Politics, 70(2), 335–350. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022381608080341
Mishra, S. (2014). Decision-Making Under Risk Integrating Perspectives From Biology, Economics, and Psychology. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 18(3), 280–307. https://doi.org/10.1177/1088868314530517
Naumof, N. (2016). Seeking Mediocrity: Humans are Hardwired to Avoid the Worst, not to Seek the Best Outcome. Retrieved April 6, 2016, from https://www.naumof.com/
Saad, G. (2011). The missing link: the biological roots of the business sciences. In G. Saad (Ed.), Evolutionary psychology in the business sciences (pp. 1–17). London: Springer. Retrieved from https://capitadiscovery.co.uk/greenwich-ac/items/702855
Scott-Phillips, T. C., Dickins, T. E., & West, S. A. (2011). Evolutionary Theory and the Ultimate–Proximate Distinction in the Human Behavioral Sciences. Perspectives on Psychological Science, 6(1), 38–47. https://doi.org/10.1177/1745691610393528
Shapira, Z. (2002). Aspiration levels and risk taking by government bond traders. Unpublished Manuscript, New York University.
Thaler, R. H. (2000). From homo economicus to homo sapiens. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(1), 133–141.
Willman, P., Fenton-O’Creevy, M., Nicholson, N., & Soane, E. (2002). Traders, managers and loss aversion in investment banking: a field study. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 27(1–2), 85–98. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0361-3682(01)00029-0
Witt, U. (2016). The evolution of consumption and its welfare effects. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 1–21. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-016-0459-3